Anatoly Kondratenko - Probabilistic Economic Theory стр 12.

Шрифт
Фон

2. The Institutional and Environmental Principle.

3. The Dynamic and Evolutionary Principle.

4. The Market-Based Trade Maximization Principle.

5. The Uncertainty and Probability Principle.

It is evident that the uncertainty and probability effects begin to play significant role in classical economies only for the markets with huge numbers of agents. We do not concern ourselves with these effects within the framework of classical economy because it is much easier to study these problems within the framework of quantum economy (see next two chapters).

2. The Economic Lagrange Equations

Let us proceed to deriving equations of motion for the classical economy shown schematically in Fig. 1. We follow the same procedure as in classical mechanics [1]. To make calculations easier, we will consider here the one-good market economy, that is, only movement in one-dimensional price space with one coordinate P. Transition to a multi-dimensional case does not cause principal complications. We will consider that by the analogy with classical mechanics [1], a state of economy comprising of N buyers and M sellers and being under the influence of the environment is fully described by establishing all prices pi and their first time t derivatives (price changing rate or velocity of movement) , where i = 1, 2, , N + M. Let p without subscripts denote the set of all prices pi for short, similar to first and second time derivatives, i.e., for velocities pi and accelerations . Due to their logic or by definition, equations of motion connect prices, velocities and accelerations. In classical mechanics they are second-order differential equations of time, their solution under assigned conditions at the moment t0, x(t0) and (t0), represents the required mechanical trajectories, x(t). We are going to derive similar equations with the same view for our economic system in the price space.

By analogy with classical mechanics we assume that these equations result from the following principle of maximization (the principle of least action or the principle of stationary action in mechanics). Namely, the action S must have the least possible value:




Fig. 1. Graphical model of an economy in the multi-dimensional PQ-space. It is displayed schematically in the conventional rectangular multi-dimensional coordinate system [P, Q] where P and Q designate all the agent price and quantity coordinate axes, respectively. Our model economy consists of the market and the external environment. The market consists of buyers (small dots) and sellers (big dots) covered by the conventional sphere. Very many people, institutions, as well as natural and other factors can represent the external environment (cross hatched area behind the sphere) of the market which exerts perturbations on market agents, pictured here by arrows pointing from environment to market.


The obtained (1) and (2) lead to equations of motion or Lagrange equations [1]:



Equations of motion represent a system of second-order N + M differential equations of time t for N + M unknown required trajectories pi(t).

These equations employ as yet an unknown Lagrange function or Lagrangian L (p, ṗ, t) which is to be found on the basis of research or experimental data. We will note that Lagrange functions were used in literature to solve a number of optimization problems of management science [3]. Let us emphasize that determination of the Lagrange function is the key problem that can only be solved in practice by making the data of theoretical calculation fit the experiment. It can not be done using theoretical methods only. But what we can do quickly is to make the first obvious trial step. Here we assume that to a certain degree of approximation, the Lagrange function resembles (in appearance only!) the Lagrange function of its physical prototype, a system of N+M point material particles with certain potentials. All assumptions made here can be thoroughly analyzed later at the second stage of investigation and left unchanged or made more accurate after comparison with the experimental data. Accomplishment of this stage will naturally require great effort and expense. For now, we will accept these assumptions and consider that Lagrange functions have the same form as those of their physical prototype, but all parameters and potentials of the economic system will be chosen on the basis of economic experience, not taken from the physical prototype. We consider that by adjusting parameters and potentials to the experiment we can smooth out the negative influence of assumptions made for solutions of equations of motion obtained in this particular way.

So, according to our approach, equations of motion in classical economy are nominally identical to those in the corresponding mechanical system. However, their constants and potentials will have another essence, other dimensions and other values. A great advantage of classical economies consists of the fact that mathematical solutions of these equations, analytical or numerical, have been found for a great number of Lagrange functions with different potentials. That is why it is of great help to apply them. Allow us to turn to relatively simple classical economies.

Let us consider a case of the classical economy with a single good, a single buyer, and a single seller, where environmental influence and interaction between a buyer and a seller can be described with the help of potentials. The Lagrangian of such an economy has the following form:



In (4) m

1

m

2

V12 p

1

p2a prioriU1p

1

tU2p2, t




This system of two differential second-order equations of time t represents equations of motion for a selected classical economy. According to their form they are identical to the equations of motion of the physical prototype in physical space. In the latter system (5), the second Newtons law of classical mechanics is designated: product of mass by acceleration equals force. And quite another matter is that potentials can be significantly different from the corresponding potentials in the physical system. We should mention once again that these potentials are to be discovered for different economies by detailed comparison of results of computation of equations of motion of economies with experimental or research data, or in other words, with data of empirical economics. At the initial stage it is natural to try to use known forms of potentials from physical theories, and we are going to do that in future. Let us note that the purchase-sale deal or transaction in the market between the buyer and the seller will take place at the time tE when their trajectories p1(tE) and p2(tE) intersect: p1(tE) = p2(tE) = pE, as it is shown in Figs. 2, 3 for the model grain market. The equilibrium value of price, pE, is indeed then the real price of the good or commodity in the market, what we refer to as the market price of the good. See formulas, figures and discussions for classical economies in Chapter I.

It is interesting that a number of some common features of classical economy with equations of motion (5) are common for almost all constants mi and potentials V12 and Ui. Let us consider a case where external potentials Ui (pi) do not depend on time and represent potentials of attraction with high potential walls at the origin of coordinates that prevent economy from moving towards the negative price region. Further potential V12 depends only on the module of price differences of the buyer and the seller p12=|p2 p1|, namely,

Ваша оценка очень важна

0
Шрифт
Фон

Помогите Вашим друзьям узнать о библиотеке

Скачать книгу

Если нет возможности читать онлайн, скачайте книгу файлом для электронной книжки и читайте офлайн.

fb2.zip txt txt.zip rtf.zip a4.pdf a6.pdf mobi.prc epub ios.epub fb3